Rhyme of a Recent Marriner
Marriner
Stoddard Eccles was born in 1890, one of twenty-one children. His father, David Eccles, was a Mormon
immigrant from Scotland who settled in Utah, married two women, became a
businessman, and made a fortune.
At the age of twenty, Marriner went to Scotland as a missionary; but he returned to Utah two years later after his father’s death. He became a bank president when he was twenty-four, and a multi-millionaire tycoon by the time he was forty. He was a director of railroad, hotel, and insurance companies, head of a bank holding company with twenty-six banks, and president of four other companies when the stock market crashed in 1929.
Thanks to his diversification, he survived the Great Crash, but the experience changed his mind. Decades later, in his memoirs, he wrote:
At the age of twenty, Marriner went to Scotland as a missionary; but he returned to Utah two years later after his father’s death. He became a bank president when he was twenty-four, and a multi-millionaire tycoon by the time he was forty. He was a director of railroad, hotel, and insurance companies, head of a bank holding company with twenty-six banks, and president of four other companies when the stock market crashed in 1929.
Thanks to his diversification, he survived the Great Crash, but the experience changed his mind. Decades later, in his memoirs, he wrote:
Men
I respected assured me that the economic crisis was only temporary and that
soon all the things that had pulled the country out of previous depressions
would operate to that same end once again.
But weeks turned to months. The
months turned to a year or more. Instead
of easing, the economic crisis worsened.
To preserve
his banks, Eccles called in loans and reduced credit, but he began to suspect
that by tightening their belts, banks were saving themselves at the expense of
the larger society, that:
in seeking
individual salvation, we were contributing to collective ruin.
Eccles was
an economist from the general equilibrium school, yet he rejected the
prevailing notion that the crisis was somehow the result of “natural economic
laws.” He saw it as the work of men:
with
great economic power [who] had an undue influence in making the rules of the
economic game, in shaping the actions of government that enforced those rules,
and in conditioning the attitude taken by people as a whole toward those
rules. After I lost faith in my business
heroes, I concluded that I and everyone else had an equal right to share in the
process by which economic rules are made and changed.
In 1933, he
testified before a Senate committee investigating the crash. He disputed the view that the downturn was
the result of previous extravagant spending, pointing instead to leveraged
debt:
The debt structure has
obtained its present astronomical proportions due to an unbalanced distribution
of wealth production as measured in buying power during our years of
prosperity. Too much of the product of labor was diverted into capital goods, and as
a result what seemed to be our prosperity was maintained on a basis of abnormal
credit both at home and abroad. (Emphasis
added.)
With so much money
flowing into financial products, there was not enough left among the middle and
lower classes to sustain spending:
This naturally reduced the demand
for goods of all kinds, bringing about what appeared to be overproduction, but
what in reality was underconsumption measured in terms of the real world and
not the money world. This naturally
brought about a falling in prices and unemployment. Unemployment further decreased the consumption
of goods, which further increased unemployment, thus bringing about a
continuing decline in prices. Earnings
began to disappear, requiring economies of all kinds — decreases in wages,
salaries, and time of those employed.
And thus the vicious cycle of
deflation was continued until after nearly four years we find one-third of our
entire working population unemployed, with prices of everything greatly
reduced, raw products of all kinds selling at an unprecedentedly low level; our
national income reduced by 50 per cent with the aggregate debt burden greater
than ever before, not in dollars but measured by present values which
represents the ability to pay; fixed charges, such as taxes, railroad and
utility rates, insurance and interest charges close to the 1929 level and
requiring such a portion of the national income to meet them that the amount
left for consumption goods is not sufficient to support the population.
Eccles understood
that demand drives the real economy. He
argued that when business fails, it is the responsibility of government to
protect the citizens by giving them the means to earn money. Unemployment means money is not being
circulated:
Of course we are losing
$2,000,000,000 per month in unemployment. I can conceive of no greater waste than the
waste of reducing our national income about half of what it was. I can not conceive of any waste as great as
that. Labor, after all, is our only
source of wealth.
I repeat there is plenty of money today to bring about a restoration of prices, but the chief trouble is that it is in the wrong place; it is concentrated in the larger financial centers of the country, the creditor sections, leaving a great portion of the back country, or the debtor sections, drained dry…During the period of the depression the creditor sections have acted on our system like a great suction pump, drawing a large portion of the available income and deposits in payment of interest, debts, insurance and dividends as well as in the transfer of balances by the larger corporations normally carried throughout the country.
I repeat there is plenty of money today to bring about a restoration of prices, but the chief trouble is that it is in the wrong place; it is concentrated in the larger financial centers of the country, the creditor sections, leaving a great portion of the back country, or the debtor sections, drained dry…During the period of the depression the creditor sections have acted on our system like a great suction pump, drawing a large portion of the available income and deposits in payment of interest, debts, insurance and dividends as well as in the transfer of balances by the larger corporations normally carried throughout the country.
Eccles presented five main
points to repair the economy — federal spending to assist the destitute and the
unemployed, works projects, regulations on business, refinancing mortgages, and
canceling the debts of our World War I allies.
Our allies could not buy our products if all their money went to debt
service. He also recommended
federal bank insurance, tax reforms, a minimum wage, unemployment insurance,
and regulation of the stock market:
Such measures as I have
proposed may frighten those of our people who possess wealth. However, they should feel reassured in
reflecting upon the following quotation from one of our leading economists:
It is utterly impossible, as this country has
demonstrated again and again, for the rich to save as much as they have been
trying to save, and save anything that is worth saving. They can save idle factories and useless
railroad coaches; they can save empty office buildings and closed banks; they
can save paper evidences of foreign loans; but as a class they can not save
anything that is worth saving, above and beyond the amount that is made profitable
by the increase of consumer buying. It
is for the interests of the well to do — to protect them from the results of
their own folly — that we should take from them a sufficient amount of their
surplus to enable consumers to consume and business to operate at a profit.
Eccles was
nominated to chair the Federal Reserve in 1934, where he served for fourteen
years. After he retired, he wrote in his
memoirs:
A
policy of adequate governmental outlays at a time when private enterprise is
curtailing its expenditures does not reflect a preference for an unbalanced
budget. It merely reflects a desire and
the need to put idle men, money and material to work. As they are put to work, and as private
enterprise is stimulated to absorb the unemployed, the budget can and should be
brought into balance, to offset the danger of a boom on the upswing, just as an
unbalanced budget could help counteract a depression on a downswing.
Eccles
concluded that the Great Depression was not caused by excessive spending in the
1920s but by the great inequality of wealth distribution:
As
mass production has to be accompanied by mass consumption, mass consumption, in
turn, implies a distribution of wealth — not of existing wealth, but of wealth
as it is currently produced — to provide men with buying power equal to the
amount of goods and services offered by the nation’s economic machinery. Instead of achieving that kind of distribution,
a giant suction pump had by 1929-1930 drawn into a few hands an increasing
portion of currently produced wealth.
This served them as capital accumulations. But by taking purchasing power out of the
hands of mass consumers, the savers denied to themselves the kind of effective
demand for their products that would justify a reinvestment of their capital
accumulations in new plants. In
consequence, as in a poker game where the chips were concentrated in fewer and
fewer hands, the other fellows could stay in the game only by borrowing. When their credit ran out, the game stopped.
The
policies developed to cope with the Great Depression served us well for years,
so of course they were opposed by the political right. Claiming that government is the problem, not
the solution, they fought successfully to eliminate the very regulations which had
saved them decades before. The Crash of
2008 was followed by the usual right-wing demand for government austerity to further cripple the economy. They wanted to save the banks at the expense
of the larger society, and they got their way. Since then, they have opposed anything and
everything that would actually help ordinary citizens. It’s 1930 all over again.
History, Mark Twain quipped, doesn’t repeat itself, but it
does sometimes rhyme. We’ve already had
another crash, so we could use another Marriner Eccles — and sooner rather than
later.
Labels: economics, Marriner Eccles